LOG IN⠴ݱâ

  • ȸ¿ø´ÔÀÇ ¾ÆÀ̵ð¿Í Æнº¿öµå¸¦ ÀÔ·ÂÇØ ÁÖ¼¼¿ä.
  • ȸ¿øÀÌ ¾Æ´Ï½Ã¸é ¾Æ·¡ [ȸ¿ø°¡ÀÔ]À» ´­·¯ ȸ¿ø°¡ÀÔÀ» ÇØÁֽñ⠹ٶø´Ï´Ù.

¾ÆÀ̵ð ÀúÀå

   

¾ÆÀ̵ð Áߺ¹°Ë»ç⠴ݱâ

HONGGIDONG ˼
»ç¿ë °¡´ÉÇÑ È¸¿ø ¾ÆÀ̵ð ÀÔ´Ï´Ù.

E-mail Áߺ¹È®ÀÎ⠴ݱâ

honggildong@naver.com ˼
»ç¿ë °¡´ÉÇÑ E-mail ÁÖ¼Ò ÀÔ´Ï´Ù.

¿ìÆí¹øÈ£ °Ë»ö⠴ݱâ

°Ë»ö

SEARCH⠴ݱâ

ºñ¹Ð¹øÈ£ ã±â

¾ÆÀ̵ð

¼º¸í

E-mail

Archive

ÅõÀÚÀºÇà°ú »ê¾÷ÀÚº»

  • °­°æÈÆ µ¿±¹´ëÇб³ °æ¿µ´ëÇÐ ±³¼ö
ÈçÈ÷ ÀÚº»½ÃÀåÀÇ ²ÉÀ¸·Î ºÒ¸®¿ì´Â ÅõÀÚÀºÇàÀÇ À°¼ºÀº ¿ì¸®³ª¶ó¿¡¼­µµ Áß¿äÇÑ °úÁ¦·Î Á¦±âµÇ¾î ¿ÔÀ¸³ª ±¹³» ±ÝÀ¶ÅõÀÚȸ»çµéÀº ¿©ÀüÈ÷ ´Ü¼øÁß°³ µî¿¡¸¸ ÁÖ·ÂÇÏ°í ÀÖÀ¸¸ç ±â¾÷¿¡ ´ëÇÑ Á¤º¸ »ý»êÀ» ¹ÙÅÁÀ¸·Î ÇÏ´Â Áõ±ÇÀÇ Àμö³ª M&A Áß°³ µîÀÇ ¾÷¹« ºñÁßÀÌ ¸Å¿ì ³·Àº ÇüÆíÀÌ´Ù. ÀÌ ³í¹®Àº ÀÌ·Ð ¸ðÇüÀ» ÅëÇØ ¿ì¸®³ª¶ó¿¡¼­¿Í °°ÀÌ »ê¾÷ÀÚº» °è¿­»ç µéÀÌ Áö¹èÀûÀÎ À§Ä¡¸¦ Â÷ÁöÇÏ´Â °æ¿ì ÅõÀÚÀºÇàÀÌ Á¦´ë·Î ¼ºÀåÇÏÁö ¸øÇÏ°Ô µÇ´Â ¹®Á¦¸¦ ºÐ¼®ÇÏ¿´´Ù. ÀÌ¿¡ µû¶ó µµÃâµÈ ÁÖ¿ä ¿¬±¸°á°ú´Â ´ÙÀ½°ú °°´Ù. ù°, »ê¾÷ÀÚº» ¼Ò¼Ó ÅõÀÚÀºÇàÀÌ °è¿­ ºñ±ÝÀ¶È¸»çÀÇ ÅõÀÚ¾ÈÀ» Æò°¡ÇÏ´Â °æ¿ì µ¶¸³°è ÅõÀÚÀºÇà¿¡ ºñÇÏ¿© Ç×»ó ÁÁÀº ÅõÀÚÀÇ°ßÀ» Á¦½ÃÇÏ´Â Á¤º¸ ¿Ö°îÀÌ ¹ß»ýÇÒ °¡´É¼ºÀÌ ³ô´Ù. µÑ°, µÎ »ê¾÷ÀÚº»ÀÌ ÅõÀÚÀºÇà°úÀÇ °áÇÕ ¿©ºÎ¸¦ °áÁ¤ÇÏ´Â °ÔÀÓ¿¡¼­ ¼øÁøÇÑ ÅõÀÚÀÚ°¡ ¸¹À»¼ö·Ï ±×¸®°í ÆòÆÇ ºñ¿ëÀÌ ÀÛÀ»¼ö·Ï (°áÇÕ, °áÇÕ)ÀÇ ±ÕÇüÀÌ ÀÌ·ç¾îÁú °¡´É¼ºÀÌ Ä¿Áø´Ù. ¸¶Áö¸·À¸·Î »ê¾÷ ÀÚº»°ú ÅõÀÚÀºÇàÀÌ °áÇյǾî ÀÖ´Â °æ¿ìÀÇ »çȸÈÄ»ý ¼öÁØÀº ºÐ¸®µÇ¾î ÀÖ´Â °æ¿ì¿¡ ºñÇÏ¿© Ç×»ó ³·°Ô µÈ´Ù´Â °ÍÀ» ¹ß°ßÇÏ¿´´Ù.
ÅõÀÚÀºÇà,Áõ±ÇÀμö,ºñ´ëĪ Á¤º¸,±Ý»êºÐ¸®,Á¤º¸ »ý»êÀÇ ¿Ö°î

Investment Banking and Commerce

  • Kyeong-Hoon Kang
Investment banks (IBs) are often viewed as key players in the capital markets because of their pivotal roles in securities businesses as underwriters. Mainly, they are most useful as producers of information or creators of information market place, often resorting to resolve the asymmetric information problems that exist in the market. Indeed, IBs¡¯ role as the providers of information to the market participants is vital for active financial markets especially for IPOs and renegotiation of corporate loan payments in times of distress. In such situations, investment banks can create added value by producing information for themselves or by designing and running a market place within which information are being produced and traded. As such, the Korean government has made a major regulatory reform so as to introduce investment banking businesses. Despite the favorable regulatory environment, Korea has witnessed thus far very little success with this endeavor as only few domestic IBs can be found in the domestic market. In general, financial companies in the Korean capital market play limited roles in stock brokerage. Other complex financial services related to securities underwriting or M&A deals are mostly performed by foreign investment banks. This paper, therefore, examines to gain better understanding what obstacles exist in Korea¡¯s capital market for securities companies to properly function as full-fledged investment banks. In particular, the paper explains theoretically that it is difficult for an investment bank, which is affiliated with non-financial firms, to produce accurate information about its non-financial affiliates or their rivals, and thus it cannot build up easily its reputation as an IB. This potential conflict of interest often gets in the way for investment banks in Korea to secure their positions in the financial market as proper IBs, or reliable information sources. The game theoretic model used in this paper is based on Bolton et al. (2012), and Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1994). The model is developed in the context of an investment bank underwriting a stock issue and there are three main participants: issuers, investment banks, and investors. Issuers approach the equity market to raise capital for their projects and market their equity either directly to potential investors or through investment banks (or underwriters). Investment banks are producers of information about the issuers. But they produce noisy evaluations of issuers¡¯ projects, which they report to investors when marketing equity in return for a fee from the issuer. Then, investors determine the market value of the equity based on the information provided by the IBs. In this paradigm, investors believe ex-ante that the project is good with the 50% probability. This lack of certainty creates room for the investment banks to perform their role using their expertise to accurately assess whether the project in hand is actually worth the investment. Investment banks obtain fees only from those firms whose equity they market. The fees charged by the investment banks are assumed to be a fraction k of the value added by their services for the issuer firms. This value added can be determined by assessing the difference between the value of equity when the investment bank is involved and the value when it is not when the issuer approaches the equity market directly without the help of an underwriter. After reviewing the report, the issuer has the choice whether to accept or refuse the investment bank¡¯s proposed evaluation report. When the issuer firm turns down the investment bank¡¯s report, it does not pay fees and the report is not disclosed. Once the investment bank¡¯s evaluation report is announced or it is known that the report has been turned down, the issuer sets a uniform price for the investment. Investors, after taking into account the evaluation report and the price, finally decide whether and how much they intend to invest. Investors are divided into two types: sophisticated and naive. Sophisticated investors observe the payoffs of the game for both the investment bank and the issuer and they understand the potential conflict of interest between the investment bank and the issuer. Yet, they are not certain whether the project is good or bad, as they only have access to the investment bank¡¯s report without being able to directly observe the IB¡¯s signals about the project. On the other hand, naive investors simply assume that investment banks always truthfully evaluate the project. The main findings from this model are as follows. First, an IB which is affiliated with non-financial firms is more likely to produce distorted information than an independent IB is. Second, non-financial conglomerates are more likely to integrate with IBs if there are more naive investors in capital markets, if the fraction k is greater, and if the reputation costs are lower. Last, social welfare produced in the case when IBs are affiliated with non-financial conglomerates is always lower than that in the case when the IBs are independent. These results imply that separation of investment banking and commerce could be an important pre-condition for the successful introduction of IBs and their development.
Investment Banking,Underwriting,Asymmetric Information,Separation of Banking and Commerce,Distortions in Information Production